Economic analysis does not support the claim
that economic growth and patenting are obviously and closely linked.
If, for example, patent activity is measured in relationship to the
growth of the gross national product (GNP), in the twentieth century one
finds a great discrepancy between the two. Since 1930 the GNP has
maintained a lead far in advance of the increase in patented
inventions. Evidence of this sort supports the conclusion of the
distinguished economist Fritz Machlup in his study of the impact of the
patent system: "No economist, on the basis of present knowledge, could
possibly state with certainty that the patent system, as it now
operates, confers a net benefit or a net loss on society." This
observation, made in 1958, still holds true today.
Originally the seventeen-year monopoly was meant
to protect inventors as they prepared their inventions for market. Once
the corporation gained control of patents, the monopoly was used to
suppress any inventions that might harm its own products or enhance
those of a rival. Furthermore, corporations use their captive inventors
to devise machines and processes that protect and perpetuate their own
patented products and encroach upon those of competitors. Social
benefits are rarely the concerns of those involved in these maneuvers.
On the other hand, small firms and individual inventors, both of whom
depend on limited monopoly for protection against large companies, would
be harmed by the end of patenting.
The existence of a large, well-staffed
laboratory does not necessarily mean that a firm is self-sufficient in
its research needs. The Du Pont Company, a recognized leader in
industrial research, maintains extensive laboratories that have been
held in high regard by its top officials. In 1950, Du Pont president
Crawford H. Greenwalt announced: "I can say categorically that our
present size and success have come about through new products and
processes that have been developed in our laboratories." Economist W.
F. Mueller, who studied the sources of Du Pont innovations during the
thirty-year period from 1920 to 1950, came to the opposite conclusion.
He found that of twenty-five important new products and processes
introduced by the company in that time only ten were based on inventions
by Du Pont's research staff. . . . The rights to fifteen innovations
produced outside the company were obtained from various firms and from
independent inventors.
The DuPont Company figures are indicative of an
important fact. The independent inventor was not displaced by the
organized research teams that swept into industry after the turn of the
century. A study of seventy of the most important inventions produced
in the first half of the twentieth century found that more than half of
these emerged from the work of independent inventors. The list of their
contributions is an impressive one and includes the automatic
transmission, Bakelite, the ballpoint pen, Cellophane, the cyclotron,
the gyro-compass, insulin, the jet engine, Kodachrome film, magnetic
recording, power steering, the safety razor, xerography, the Wankel
rotary-piston engine, and the zipper fastener.
Basalla [1988, 121-128].
ç
Prior Page of Text
Next Page of Text
è
(C) 2005-2014 Wayne M. Angel.
All rights reserved. |